Jump to content

mpauls

Member
  • Posts

    350
  • Joined

  • Last visited

Everything posted by mpauls

  1. http://www4.gsb.columbia.edu/null?&exclusive=filemgr.download&file_id=7213933 Feature Interview: Mason Hawkins Chief Executive Officer, Portfolio Manager, and Chairman, Southeastern Asset Management "Parsimony is Extremely Profitable" G&D: A lot of people talk about value investing, but what does value investing mean to you and how does that differentiate your firm? Mason Hawkins: Graham provided the definition in the Intelligent Investor. An investment is one that promises safety of principal and an adequate return. By deduction, those that don’t are speculators. We believe that buying securities at large discounts to conservative appraisals provides the best route to above average compounding. We’re focused on nailing down our evaluations so we can use them to make significant long-term investment commitments when sellers are under duress or traders are consumed with ephemeral short-term issues. Mason Hawkins founded Southeastern Asset Management in 1975, and today the firm manages over $30 billion in value investments. The firm built on its tremendous track record in 2009, with its Longleaf Partners Fund posting its best absolute annual return of nearly 54%
  2. He paid a pretty penny and I'm certain he would not have paid a penny more. He paid for something he usually doesn't pay for.
  3. I love Float. I also love that I've never seen anyone value it properly. p.s. Junto I like the name.
  4. I did a write-up last year that walks through some of Berkshire's complexities. For those interested you can view it here: http://issuu.com/mpauls/docs/berkshirehathawayvaluation2009 Not much has changed since last year in terms of valuation. If I decide to update the write up I'll be sure to post it here.
  5. Sorry, unintended implication. Meant simply that there is a limit to the knowledge he's willing to share and he reached that limit long ago.
  6. Buffett doesn't slip, but you can tell he isn't too fond of the deal. Even worse, he cut me off a long time ago and simply won't teach me anything new.
  7. I listened to the call the other day, but I skipped through. Let's ignore specifics for simplicity and to get a clear picture of the transaction separate from from strategic intention. As I understand, CCE currently owns rights to KO's US bottling distribution. KO controls several international bottlers. KO owns 37% of CCE. The transaction: In exchange for KO's 37% and two (NOR and SWE) or so European bottlers, KO takes ownership and consolidates CCE's US bottlers. KO is effectively severing several controlling interests of European Bottling businesses. Given CCE's option to acquire the German bottling operation, it appears as though they want to separate the European bottling business completely. There was some anti-trust study by the European Union on Coca-Cola in 2006-a prelim investigation for which I found no follow up, but honestly didn't dig too deeply. P.s. "Muhtar Kent explains this reason at 1:22:00/1:44:09" The stream that I access is only 1:03.
  8. ... it doesn't make much sense having two bottlers, one in house and one externally managed, when one would be a lot simpler and nimbler given beverage trends. Then why keep the US/Canada distribution?
  9. Every time they have to negotiate one of their new products with their bottlers, they end up with all this friction in the supply chain." Distilling the fundamental conflict between manufacturer and bottler, he explained that "bottlers want syrup prices lower and finished-product prices higher, while Coke wants the opposite, so they keep arguing with their bottlers."
  10. Keep Digging guy's. I recently got interested in this transaction, but I have no satisfactory explanation for this. No trace in either TCCC or CCE's reports. I wonder about Euro competition issues. Also there was comment about much higher cost of debt for CCE, which TCCC would obviously finance for much less. That said, doesn't look like there is any difficulty in making these payments. There has to be a very clear answer, but I am yet to come up with or hear anything close. Keep throwing some ideas out there to stimulate ideas and discussion.
  11. http://www.heraldtribune.com/section/opinion090106
  12. http://www.slate.com/id/2245328/pagenum/all/ Basically, It's Over: A parable about how one nation came to financial ruin. By Charles Munger Updated Sunday, Feb. 21, 2010, at 3:30 PM ET In the early 1700s, Europeans discovered in the Pacific Ocean a large, unpopulated island with a temperate climate, rich in all nature's bounty except coal, oil, and natural gas. Reflecting its lack of civilization, they named this island "Basicland." The Europeans rapidly repopulated Basicland, creating a new nation. They installed a system of government like that of the early United States. There was much encouragement of trade, and no internal tariff or other impediment to such trade. Property rights were greatly respected and strongly enforced. The banking system was simple. It adapted to a national ethos that sought to provide a sound currency, efficient trade, and ample loans for credit-worthy businesses while strongly discouraging loans to the incompetent or for ordinary daily purchases. Moreover, almost no debt was used to purchase or carry securities or other investments, including real estate and tangible personal property. The one exception was the widespread presence of secured, high-down-payment, fully amortizing, fixed-rate loans on sound houses, other real estate, vehicles, and appliances, to be used by industrious persons who lived within their means. Speculation in Basicland's security and commodity markets was always rigorously discouraged and remained small. There was no trading in options on securities or in derivatives other than "plain vanilla" commodity contracts cleared through responsible exchanges under laws that greatly limited use of financial leverage. In its first 150 years, the government of Basicland spent no more than 7 percent of its gross domestic product in providing its citizens with essential services such as fire protection, water, sewage and garbage removal, some education, defense forces, courts, and immigration control. A strong family-oriented culture emphasizing duty to relatives, plus considerable private charity, provided the only social safety net. The tax system was also simple. In the early years, governmental revenues came almost entirely from import duties, and taxes received matched government expenditures. There was never much debt outstanding in the form of government bonds. As Adam Smith would have expected, GDP per person grew steadily. Indeed, in the modern area it grew in real terms at 3 percent per year, decade after decade, until Basicland led the world in GDP per person. As this happened, taxes on sales, income, property, and payrolls were introduced. Eventually total taxes, matched by total government expenditures, amounted to 35 percent of GDP. The revenue from increased taxes was spent on more government-run education and a substantial government-run social safety net, including medical care and pensions. A regular increase in such tax-financed government spending, under systems hard to "game" by the unworthy, was considered a moral imperative—a sort of egality-promoting national dividend—so long as growth of such spending was kept well below the growth rate of the country's GDP per person. Basicland also sought to avoid trouble through a policy that kept imports and exports in near balance, with each amounting to about 25 percent of GDP. Some citizens were initially nervous because 60 percent of imports consisted of absolutely essential coal and oil. But, as the years rolled by with no terrible consequences from this dependency, such worry melted away. Basicland was exceptionally creditworthy, with no significant deficit ever allowed. And the present value of large "off-book" promises to provide future medical care and pensions appeared unlikely to cause problems, given Basicland's steady 3 percent growth in GDP per person and restraint in making unfunded promises. Basicland seemed to have a system that would long assure its felicity and long induce other nations to follow its example—thus improving the welfare of all humanity. But even a country as cautious, sound, and generous as Basicland could come to ruin if it failed to address the dangers that can be caused by the ordinary accidents of life. These dangers were significant by 2012, when the extreme prosperity of Basicland had created a peculiar outcome: As their affluence and leisure time grew, Basicland's citizens more and more whiled away their time in the excitement of casino gambling. Most casino revenue now came from bets on security prices under a system used in the 1920s in the United States and called "the bucket shop system." The winnings of the casinos eventually amounted to 25 percent of Basicland's GDP, while 22 percent of all employee earnings in Basicland were paid to persons employed by the casinos (many of whom were engineers needed elsewhere). So much time was spent at casinos that it amounted to an average of five hours per day for every citizen of Basicland, including newborn babies and the comatose elderly. Many of the gamblers were highly talented engineers attracted partly by casino poker but mostly by bets available in the bucket shop systems, with the bets now called "financial derivatives." Many people, particularly foreigners with savings to invest, regarded this situation as disgraceful. After all, they reasoned, it was just common sense for lenders to avoid gambling addicts. As a result, almost all foreigners avoided holding Basicland's currency or owning its bonds. They feared big trouble if the gambling-addicted citizens of Basicland were suddenly faced with hardship. And then came the twin shocks. Hydrocarbon prices rose to new highs. And in Basicland's export markets there was a dramatic increase in low-cost competition from developing countries. It was soon obvious that the same exports that had formerly amounted to 25 percent of Basicland's GDP would now only amount to 10 percent. Meanwhile, hydrocarbon imports would amount to 30 percent of GDP, instead of 15 percent. Suddenly Basicland had to come up with 30 percent of its GDP every year, in foreign currency, to pay its creditors. How was Basicland to adjust to this brutal new reality? This problem so stumped Basicland's politicians that they asked for advice from Benfranklin Leekwanyou Vokker, an old man who was considered so virtuous and wise that he was often called the "Good Father." Such consultations were rare. Politicians usually ignored the Good Father because he made no campaign contributions. Among the suggestions of the Good Father were the following. First, he suggested that Basicland change its laws. It should strongly discourage casino gambling, partly through a complete ban on the trading in financial derivatives, and it should encourage former casino employees—and former casino patrons—to produce and sell items that foreigners were willing to buy. Second, as this change was sure to be painful, he suggested that Basicland's citizens cheerfully embrace their fate. After all, he observed, a man diagnosed with lung cancer is willing to quit smoking and undergo surgery because it is likely to prolong his life. The views of the Good Father drew some approval, mostly from people who admired the fiscal virtue of the Romans during the Punic Wars. But others, including many of Basicland's prominent economists, had strong objections. These economists had intense faith that any outcome at all in a free market—even wild growth in casino gambling—is constructive. Indeed, these economists were so committed to their basic faith that they looked forward to the day when Basicland would expand real securities trading, as a percentage of securities outstanding, by a factor of 100, so that it could match the speculation level present in the United States just before onslaught of the Great Recession that began in 2008. The strong faith of these Basicland economists in the beneficence of hypergambling in both securities and financial derivatives stemmed from their utter rejection of the ideas of the great and long-dead economist who had known the most about hyperspeculation, John Maynard Keynes. Keynes had famously said, "When the capital development of a country is the byproduct of the operations of a casino, the job is likely to be ill done." It was easy for these economists to dismiss such a sentence because securities had been so long associated with respectable wealth, and financial derivatives seemed so similar to securities. Basicland's investment and commercial bankers were hostile to change. Like the objecting economists, the bankers wanted change exactly opposite to change wanted by the Good Father. Such bankers provided constructive services to Basicland. But they had only moderate earnings, which they deeply resented because Basicland's casinos—which provided no such constructive services—reported immoderate earnings from their bucket-shop systems. Moreover, foreign investment bankers had also reported immoderate earnings after building their own bucket-shop systems—and carefully obscuring this fact with ingenious twaddle, including claims that rational risk-management systems were in place, supervised by perfect regulators. Naturally, the ambitious Basicland bankers desired to prosper like the foreign bankers. And so they came to believe that the Good Father lacked any understanding of important and eternal causes of human progress that the bankers were trying to serve by creating more bucket shops in Basicland. Of course, the most effective political opposition to change came from the gambling casinos themselves. This was not surprising, as at least one casino was located in each legislative district. The casinos resented being compared with cancer when they saw themselves as part of a long-established industry that provided harmless pleasure while improving the thinking skills of its customers. As it worked out, the politicians ignored the Good Father one more time, and the Basicland banks were allowed to open bucket shops and to finance the purchase and carry of real securities with extreme financial leverage. A couple of economic messes followed, during which every constituency tried to avoid hardship by deflecting it to others. Much counterproductive governmental action was taken, and the country's credit was reduced to tatters. Basicland is now under new management, using a new governmental system. It also has a new nickname: Sorrowland.
  13. Anyone wish to explain what justifies Whitney Tilson. Particularly why people support his Value investing Congress, especially at $3,000 per head (discounted). Ok, good speakers, but this guy really rubs me the wrong way.
  14. Here is a site that I believe was put up by Irving Kahn specifically for that book. http://www.bufferstock.org/frames.htm http://www.bufferstock.org/wcwcbook.htm
  15. How old are you? You are young and should do nothing other than term life. You're buying life insurance not an investment. When they start offering you anything other than life, pass. Term life insurance gets expensive as you age (for obvious reasons) but the need for it also declines if you have saved appropriately. Once your kids are capable of taking care of themselves you may no longer need life insurance. I put together something for a friend a few years back detailing the benefits of buying term life and investing the difference between term and what you would otherwise pay for ordinary life over time. I attached a pdf which board members will find below. May take a minute or two to figure out what, but you'll see what I mean. The two columns on the right side are investment returns. Investing a portion of your premium with the options provided by the insurer will not yield you anything better than 8% annually and likely more like 5%. If you are a relatively smart investor you should be able to get between 10-15% on your own (far right column).
  16. http://www.insideinfluence.com/
  17. Bloomberg Ticker - NBPC LN Reuters Ticker - NBPC.L Yes I have a position in it.
  18. forgot I had this: http://www.synthesispartners.net/synthesisdocs/interconnectedness.png So there are several on this list that are unaccounted for: Notables Glenn Greenberg's Chieftain Capital, Price's MFP Capital, Sonkin's Hummingbird Capital, and others.
  19. Unless you are a partner you will not find much info on Brookdale International Partners, except for an isolated single year performance figure. They are a small fund and invest in complex mis-pricings of all kinds. They are quite similar to Baupost. Though they do not tend to hold much cash, they employ very little risk. In no single year since the 1980's have they lost money. The first part is creating a list, the second part would be to look at the list in more detail, determine which funds or managers did well because they acted sensibly and which did well for no reason of their own. This second part comes later, so don't worry if there are oranges among apples at this point. Indeed this is partly true. True to the extent that we are talking about the best, separate from just good (e.g., Bill Miller=good, Seth Klarman, Buffett=Best) Once you ID the "Best" I would agree the difference is small, however identifying them is much more difficult simply because they don't want you to find or ID them. That is, this task is complicated by the difficulty of acquiring performance figures. The point of this list is not only to compile really good funds and managers, but to identify their performances with some level of detail or fact. So there are many people who are thought to be good because they manage many billions, not as a function of compounding, but a function of marketing.
  20. Those of you impressed by Paulson's returns, prepare yourselves. recall, since 1994, Paulson Partners LP = 17%. S&P = 8.8% Merger Arb = 8.7% Hedge Fund Index = 6.7% So Paulson did slightly better than 3x the market. You may need to sit down. Since 1991, Brookdale International Partners did better than 20x the markets, with very little risk.
×
×
  • Create New...