Jump to content

vinod1

Member
  • Posts

    1,667
  • Joined

  • Last visited

  • Days Won

    4

Posts posted by vinod1

  1. This is one of the better letters from Hussman.

     

    The key issue is the level of profit margins going forward compared to the past. Hussman is betting that profit margins revert around the 6% level. I have absolutely no doubt that profit margins are mean reverting but think the mean they would be reverting would be higher than in the past. This is sort of like the old rule of dividend yield for stocks should be higher than the bond yields since stocks are risky. This used to be a good indicator for when stocks are getting overvalued. Anyone following it would have been out of stocks for about 55 years from the mid 1950s till about march 2009. The point being, big macro calls could turn out to be wrong for very long periods of time, far longer than the investment horizon of most people. I agree stocks are pretty highly valued, just not as much as Hussman thinks or as certain as he seems to be that they would come crashing down.

     

    Vinod

     

     

  2. Imo, what you have written makes a lot of sense, and I think anyone who follows your example, including having an effective mean to constantly replenish his cash, is on his way to beat the market handsomely.

    My perspective, though, is a little bit different. And it stems from my deeply ingrained skepticism about being truly able to understand a business and to forecast its future results.

    Let me make this very simplified example: suppose for a moment that the whole market is composed by only two companies: Berkshire Hathaway and Wells Fargo, equally weighted. Now, the market plunges -40%. And it plunges this way: -30% for BRK stock price, -50% for WFC stock price. Before the plunge you were fully invested in BRK, and now you are saying: “Ok, my currency depreciated by -30%, but now I have the opportunity to purchase WFC, which is down -50%! Very good bargain!!”

    That’s exactly when my skepticism comes in, playing the role of the joy killer… What do I really know about WFC, that other people don’t?! …Well, nothing…!! And that is it for me… I cannot invest… Beware: this is just me… It is just how I am done… Probably, it is a deep flaw of mine! And it shouldn’t apply to anybody else!

    You see? My “fat pitch” is different from yours: my fat pitch is BRK that has come down -30%. After all, by now I must have spent thousands of hours studying BRK, and almost nothing studying WFC… So, how could I swing to that perfect pitch, without any dry powder left?

     

    giofranchi

     

     

    I agree with Giofranchi having lived through an almost exact scenario in the 2008-2009 crisis. I went into the 2008-2009 crisis with about 70% cash and I had been able to take advantage of the market behaviour in that period nearly perfectly buy a lot in Oct/Nov 2008, trim a bit in Dec, load up in Feb/March 2009. The one thing I have not been able to do however is sell BRK at the lows in 2009 to buy other more attractive stocks. I was able to do it with cash I had, but for the life of me I cannot pull the trigger to sell BRK when you know with a near certanity it is less than 50% of IV and buy other stocks that are at 20-25% of IV. This is my one regret from that period but even going forward I doubt if I would be able to pull this off.

     

    Vinod

  3. A member on the Fool message board who has done some research on MF. Some very interesting results.

     

    http://boards.fool.com/brk-shareholders-mtg-30027775.aspx?sort=whole#30027775

     

     

    Note, reputable studies (including my own) generally show market beating

    performance, but the advantage is a fraction of what is claimed.

    A typical test of mine: buy the 6 highest-ranked stocks each 3 months

    and hold for a year, a portfolio of 24 stocks--about what he recommends.

    Total return 1989-2011 14.7% versus 9.3% for the S&P, advantage 5.4% without trading costs.

    This particular test limits itself to the largest 1000-1500 US stocks

    meeting [best guess of] his industry filters, so the big outperformance

    if any must lie in very small stocks. Other tests including the very

    small stocks also found only small advantages.

     

    What can I say?

    A large number of people have tested this.

    Only one, Mr Greenblatt, got really high returns from it.

    The exact reason isn't very important--it's not a foolproof money spinner.

     

    Having spent over a decade examining tens of thousands of quantitative

    investing methods, I have never seen a single plausible scheme that

    showed 30% returns with annual holds while long equities all the time

    even in backtest, let alone in real life. Maybe a few systems with

    tortuously complex over-fix filter criteria, but I can't even remember one of those.

    I don't imagine even Jim Simons could manage it, and he's the Gretzky of quants.

  4. I used to keep an eye on him a few years back ( in 2001-2003 time frame) and from what I learned he is extremely obsessed with beating the S&P 500 more than anything. He would keep track hour by hour his relative performance. He would much rather prefer a 50% loss if S&P 500 loses more than 50% than a large gain that under performs the index. He is more of a contrarian investor rather than a margin of safety kind of investor. I realized pretty quickly he is not someone worth keeping track of and kind of lost track of him after that.

     

    Vinod

  5.  

    Vinod1, I am not so sure… FFH BV per share increased 53%, 21% and 33% in 2007, in 2008 and in 2009. Its share price increased 24%, 36% and 5% in 2007, in 2008 and in 2009. Better than cash, right?  ;)

     

    giofranchi

     

     

    giofranchi,

     

    That is almost entirely due to the CDS gains. I do not see that happen in a market crash going forward.

     

    I am referring to the fact that if Fairfax did not have CDS gains I think it would have declined along with BRK, LUK, etc. I have benefited a lot from Fairfax during that period but I do not expect a repeat performance. Also I think Market would probably give us some time to load up on Fairfax if any deflation hedges look like they would be a home run. Hence, my preference for cash as a hedge instead of Fairfax. I could be wrong but that is the only way I can sleep well with my portfolio.

     

    Vinod

     

     

  6. Too high profit margins (pre-tax) are typically taken care of by competition among enterprises who are attracted by them for deployment of their own capital. Just like at Apple where they are forced to invest more to develop new products and/or by competitors selling similar devices at lower prices reducing Apple sales growth.

     

    What Buffett described in the 1999 Fortune article that would be related to income inequality was the share of corporate profits after-tax vs GDP. Not high profit margins pre-tax. I just think that we need to be careful about what margins we are talking about. Also need to realize that countries are competing for capital and jobs so if you simply tax more to reduce that share, one will offer lower corporate tax rates attracting enterprises at home. It is a fine balance. Education, currencies, interest rates, taxes, regulations, cost of living, even climate all matter. Whoever believes that they can predict accurately the direction of the economy is a fool considering the inter-relationships between all these factors and many more that I have not listed.

     

    One thing that I am absolutely sure of however is that there is no free lunch with anything. Many people fail to realize this and think that governments are different. Maybe because they are large and tough to understand, but at the end of the day, it is an entity competing with other entities (countries) for the development of their GDP and citizens. QE, unending deficits and unaffordable entitlements are not free as some on this board seem to imply. There will be consequences as some countries who are more competitive, let the law of free markets prevail and make more sacrifices should come out on top over time.

     

    Cardboard

     

    Dont Corporate profit margins and Corporate profits as a percent of GDP go hand in hand? Sales in the economy overall do not change dramatically and tax rates have been stable so I would think that they tend to track pretty closely.

     

    Vinod

     

     

  7.  

    Hi Vinod, Just curious.  Do you still hold FFH?

     

    I wonder sometime how they will do going forward.  I think the route to greater profits for them involves expanding the insurance businesses that are profitable, investing the float in wholly owned businesses or partnerships such as Kennedy Wilson.

     

    Hi Uccmal,

     

    I sold FFH at around $420 primarily due to a major portfolio overhaul in 2011. Given all the economic issues in Europe and its potential impact on US, along with US own set of issues and the opportunity set that is available (BAC/AIG/C/GS), I wanted to have a barbell type portfolio. A large allocation of cash (60-75%) coupled with high leverage via warrants and LEAPS on deeply undervalued businesses. I know FFH is hedged but if 2008-2009 crisis taught me anything it is that only cash is truly liquid. So I sold out of FFH.

     

    If BAC or AIG works out while FFH is still available around book I would revert back to FFH. I do not see underwriting profits or growth in float making much of difference to growth in book value. Growth will again likely come from portfolio performance but with the hedges in place the macro has to cooperate.

     

    Vinod

  8. I wonder how we would view Fairfax if 2008-2009 crisis did not turn out as it did. It is not like the 2008 crisis is a near certanity, so if the crisis had been more contained with housing only declining a little bit and stock market (S&P 500) declining to say only 1100 and with CDS not paying all that much, I would think Fairfax would have a book value of around $200 only at this time. So that would be a 12 year near flatlining of book value, but for the 2008-2009 crisis.

     

    I am not trying to take away Prem's achievements, I think they made a very astute macro economic bet (let us say where the odds are 80/20 or some such high number) but they had been a little lucky that it played out in their favor. Now, they are making another bet, which I agree with, but this time it could end up hurting Fairfax in terms of lost opportunity cost.

     

    Vinod

     

    But isn't there more to earn by keeping their capital strength and strong ratings at all times and then be able to increase the float when opportunities are good?

     

    I agree with the need for keeping capital strength and strong ratings and hedging does provide that benefit. However, I do not think the ability to write more business in hard markets adds all that much to Fairfax IV. I have long given up on expecting any underwriting profits from Fairfax. :) Value is predominantly going to be created by the investing abilities of HWIC.

     

    My main point is that most of the value created in the last decade has been due to a macro bet that succeeded. Fairfax now is much better positioned going forward but even with that it would need its macro bets to come through to get to the 15% annual BV growth. In a scenario where their macro bet does not play out successfully I think 15% BV growth is too optimistic unless Watsa pulls out another rabbit out of his hat.

     

    Vinod

  9. I wonder how we would view Fairfax if 2008-2009 crisis did not turn out as it did. It is not like the 2008 crisis is a near certanity, so if the crisis had been more contained with housing only declining a little bit and stock market (S&P 500) declining to say only 1100 and with CDS not paying all that much, I would think Fairfax would have a book value of around $200 only at this time. So that would be a 12 year near flatlining of book value, but for the 2008-2009 crisis.

     

    I am not trying to take away Prem's achievements, I think they made a very astute macro economic bet (let us say where the odds are 80/20 or some such high number) but they had been a little lucky that it played out in their favor. Now, they are making another bet, which I agree with, but this time it could end up hurting Fairfax in terms of lost opportunity cost.

     

    Vinod

  10. Looking at this particular point in time, I like FAIRX allocation with about 50% in AIG/BAC. I would expect FAAFX to have better returns over the long term, for reasons already mentioned by others. I split the investment equally between them.

     

    Vinod

  11. Feeding the Dragon - GMO paper on Chinese credit bubble.

     

    https://www.gmo.com/America/CMSAttachmentDownload.aspx?target=JUBRxi51IIA6KcUdqlSIwIXyKFLDu0ahgi%2fVwwPhMBjQBiRm%2bRLnDmOmauuxY3ieIGb5rFygoEWoFXDEs8Gu%2bAyctYJBUNhPmb9KxTYFrE8%3d

     

    From a valuation perspective, Chinese equities do not, at first glance, look to be a likely candidate for trouble. The PE

    ratios are either 12 or 15 times on MSCI China, depending on whether you include financials or not, and the market

    has underperformed MSCI Emerging by about 10% over the last three years (ending December 31, 2012). Neither

    of these characteristics screams “bubble.” And yet, China has been a source of worry for us over the past three years

    and continues to be one, affecting not merely our behavior with regards to stocks domiciled in China but the entire

    emerging world, as well as some specific developed market stocks, which we believe are particularly vulnerable

    should things in China go down the road we fear it might.

     

    Vinod

  12.  

    Vinod,

    thank you for everything you have written. All your thoughts are very well expressed and convincing. I agree with all of them. I probably misunderstood Mr. Krugman’s point. When I speak of debt, I always think about TOTAL debt. Because total debt is what really matters. So I implicitly thought he was advocating a further increase in total debt as a percentage of GDP... Now you have explained to me that his idea is to increase only government debt, while decreasing private debt, hoping that way to slowly decrease total debt to a more manageable level.

    In fact, that is something I can understand.  ;)

    What I still don’t understand is why people choose to point at 1929, when they don’t like to leave the markets alone, and never refer to the Weimar Republic in Germany or Japan during the last 20 years. First of all, the Great Depression saw mixed policies: from 1929 until 1932 the markets were left to adjust alone, just like Mr. Mellon suggested. But from 1933 until 1937 the New Deal implemented some of the most interventionist policies ever conceived. The results from 1938 until 1949 were far from convincing… Second, the examples of the Weimar Republic and recent Japan clearly show that government interventions might fail to be very useful.

    So, here is my “view of the world”, as you put it: there is no easy way out.

    I don’t know of a single MAJOR (there are some exceptions, like Canada in the ‘90s and others, but they all were on a far smaller scale) deleveraging in history which didn’t have bad consequences. Let the markets alone: restructurings: bad consequences. Intervene: austerity + inflation: bad consequences. A little bit of restructurings + a little bit of austerity + a little bit of inflation: probably the best solution: bad consequences.

    My view of the world: the moment you get into debt, you are screwed up.

    Mr. Vanderbilt said about debt: “If you had bought a hundred shares instead of a thousand, you could have held on. Never be in too great hurry to get rich.”

    So, here is the only true solution! I repeat: “Never be in too great hurry to get rich.” As long as we won’t be able to control and subdue our greed and ego, nothing will change, and we will always get into trouble. Once in trouble: bad consequences.

    So, I don’t believe in anyone who claims to possess the only right formula to get us out of this mess like a walk in the park. To me they are just charlatans.

    Where does this all lead me? Well, it actually has some investing implications. If most asset classes are far from cheap, not many bargains can be found, and bad consequences are possibly lurking down the road, I would be very careful… meaning that I would pile on cash reserves.

    Right now is the time where I prefer to own “a hundred shares instead of a thousand”.

     

    giofranchi

     

    giofranchi

     

    1. To your point about comparing to Weimar Republic in Germany or Japan during the last 20 years.

     

    I do not think US position now can be compared to Weimar Republic in Germany of 1920's. The magnitude of the monetary increase is several orders of magnitude higher in Germany. When we are talking about inflation in US we are talking about 3%, 4% or 5% or even high single digits. Compared to US GDP, all the US monetary increase is still a smallish number compared to the increases required for hyperinflation.

     

    The situation US is in could be compared to either 1929 GD in US or Japan in the last 20 years. As Richard Koo points out these are both cases of a "Balance Sheet Recession". Here a lot of private sector balance sheets needs to be repaired. The defining characteristic of this case is that private sector moves away from their usual profit maximization to debt minimization.

     

    Japan's stock market is down 75% from its peak, whiles its real estate is down 70% from its peak. The fact that they have been able to avoid a great depression type economic contraction, I think they did pretty good. Given that US has been much more aggressive I think US would do much better compared to Japan.

     

    Either way there is a price to be paid and it might end up as either sub par economic growth for a while, higher inflation, more economic uncertanity, etc.

     

    2. To you point about "once you go into debt you are screwed". I agree and think most of the policy makers realize this as well but they cannot come out and say that. It is now a matter of coming out of this with the as little collateral damage as possible.

     

    3. To your point about investment implications. I have no idea of how this all plays out, only thing I know is that risk is much much higher than normal.  The prices of overall market in general does not seem to reflect this risk. So I have repositioned my portfolio for the last two years with this in mind. This means several things:

    - Portfolio with much higher cash allocation.

    - Strict selling criteria. Selling any business which exceeds 80% of IV unless there is a clear and imminent catalyst.

    - Portfolio concentrated on extreme value leveraged via LEAPS or Warrants. So I can have like a 80% nominal portfolio exposure while having very roughly around 70% cash.

     

    Vinod

  13. giofranchi,

     

    Some info on the liquidationist school:

     

    http://www.mannmuseum.com/american-policies-during-the-great-depression/2/

     

    Contemplating the wreck of his country's economy and his own political career, Herbert Hoover wrote bitterly in retrospect about those in his administration who had advised inaction during the downslide:

     

    The 'leave-it-alone liquidationists' headed by Secretary of the Treasury Mellon felt that government must keep its hands off and let the slump liquidate itself. Mr. Mellon had only one formula: 'Liquidate labor, liquidate stocks, liquidate the farmers, liquidate real estate'. He held that even panic was not altogether a bad thing. He said: 'It will purge the rottenness out of the system. High costs of living and high living will come down. People will work harder, live a more moral life. Values will be adjusted, and enterprising people will pick up the wrecks from less competent people'

     

    But Hoover had been one of the most enthusiastic proponents of "liquidationism" during the Great Depression. And the unwillingness to use policy to prop up the economy during the slide into the Depression was backed by a large chorus, and approved by the most eminent economists.

     

    For example, from Harvard Joseph Schumpeter argued that there was a "presumption against remedial measures which work through money and credit. Policies of this class are particularly apt to produce additional trouble for the future." From Schumpeter's perspective, "depressions are not simply evils, which we might attempt to suppress, but forms of something which has to be done, namely, adjustment to change." This socially productive function of depressions creates "the chief difficulty" faced by economic policy makers. For "most of what would be effective in remedying a depression would be equally effective in preventing this adjustment."

     

    From London, Friedrich Hayek found it:

     

    ...still more difficult to see what lasting good effects can come from credit expansion. The thing which is most needed to secure healthy conditions is the most speedy and complete adaptation possible of the structure of production. If the proportion as determined by the voluntary decisions of individuals is distorted by the creation of artificial demand resources [are] again led into a wrong direction and a definite and lasting adjustment is again postponed. The only way permanently to 'mobilize' all available resources is, therefore to leave it to time to effect a permanent cure by the slow process of adapting the structure of production...

     

    Hayek and company believed that enterprises are gambles which sometimes fail: a future comes to pass in which certain investments should not have been made. The best that can be done in such circumstances is to shut down those production processes that turned out to have been based on assumptions about future demands that did not come to pass. The liquidation of such investments and businesses releases factors of production from unprofitable uses; they can then be redeployed in other sectors of the technologically dynamic economy. Without the initial liquidation the redeployment cannot take place. And, said Hayek, depressions are this process of liquidation and preparation for the redeployment of resources.

     

    As Schumpeter put it, policy does not allow a choice between depression and no depression, but between depression now and a worse depression later: "inflation pushed far enough [would] undoubtedly turn depression into the sham prosperity so familiar from European postwar experience, [and]... would, in the end, lead to a collapse worse than the one it was called in to remedy." For "recovery is sound only if it does come of itself. For any revival which is merely due to artificial stimulus leaves part of the work of depressions undone and adds, to an undigested remnant of maladjustment, new maladjustment of its own which has to be liquidated in turn, thus threatening business with another [worse] crisis ahead"

     

    This doctrine--that in the long run the Great Depression would turn out to have been "good medicine" for the economy, and that proponents of stimulative policies were shortsighted enemies of the public welfare--drew anguished cries of dissent from those less hindered by their theoretical blinders. British economist Ralph Hawtrey scorned those who, like Robbins and Hayek, wrote at the nadir of the Great Depression that the greatest danger the economy faced was inflation. It was, Hawtrey said, the equivalent of "Crying, 'Fire! Fire!' in Noah's flood."

     

    Vinod

  14.  

    Well Vinod, if you believe that… As far as I am concerned, only a professor or a journalist could have written something like that… Listen, I really hate complicated things. Because they might seem brilliant and convincing, but they just don’t work. Every businessman knows that. In business the only things that work are the ones easiest to implement and the outcome of which is almost certain. Everything else is a waste of time and resources 90% of the times.

    In a system much more complex than a single business, like the global economies are, the principle of simplicity should be followed even more rigorously. Krugman writes:

     

    What can be done? One answer is to find some way to reduce the real value of the debt. Debt relief could do this; so could inflation, if you can get it

     

    That’s simple.

     

    To cure the debt problem with more debt… I don’t understand how it should work: so, either I am dumb, or it is too complicated.

    Probably, the former.  :(

     

    giofranchi

     

    No, no, no. I think you choose not to understand since it does not conform to your view of the world. :) I do that all the time.

     

    On this particular issue, I have changed my own opinion on this a couple of years back. I would lay out my understanding briefly and you can point out where you disagree. I am talking just about US here.

     

    Consumers took out more debt than they can service over the past several years for a variety of reasons (housing bubble, easy loans, falling interest rates, central bank encouragement, stagnating wages, etc.). The financial crisis of 2008-2009 with falling asset prices, unemployment, etc made debt servicing more difficult for consumers who have logically pulled back from spending and started saving, thus beginning the process of reducing debt levels. The reduced spending by consumers creates headwinds for the economy resulting in sub par growth and also reduces government revenues.

     

    The government at this time can choose not to do much and just let nature take its course and let those who have recklessly borrowed more money suffer. The result would be that economy would take a much sharper downturn, housing and other assets deflate, bad banks get wiped out, lenders take haircuts on the money lent. Once this process works through, economy regains strength. The problem with this approach is that it would cause tremendous suffering. We are probably talking about GDP declines of peak to trough of something like 10-15%, unemployment shooting to 20%, etc. Jim Grant, Hussman, Rodriguez and many others think this should be the process that should be followed. There is a moral component to this line of reasoning.

     

    This approach has been argued as the quicker way to resolve the crisis, but we cannot be sure about that. We have tried this in 1929 with disastrous results.

     

    The other approach has been for Government to step in and try to take debt for a while as the consumer slowly deleverages. The Government does take on debt so Government spending would try to offset some of the reduction in spending by consumers. Monetary policy is kept as loose as possible via various mechanisms to allow borrowers to deleverage via lower interest rates or via higher inflation. We do know this is not sustainable for ever and this is not without risks. But this would be the best of the bad options.

     

    Vinod

  15.  

    I think that Mr. Paul is pointing out something obvious: things have consequences, choices have consequences. And you cannot escape those consequences, simply printing more and more money. We are at the end of a 70-years debt super-cycle, that has happened over and over again trough history. You cannot party for 70 years, and then find a magical solution to feel no hangover! Of course, things can change, we are not doomed to repeat the past. But the right change would be to prevent unsustainable debt accumulation in the first place. Once the reckless path has been followed again, there is no magic wand (or magic printing press!) to avert the inevitable consequences.

    I think that’s what Mr. Paul is warning us against. Is he right? I don’t know… we will see… But it makes sense to me, and I always like someone who warns me of possible dangers ahead.

     

    giofranchi

     

    No one is saying there is a magical solution. That is a strawman argument. Monetary policy is not the right tool to fight a liquidity trap, but Fed is doing what it can with the tools it has.

     

    From "End the Depression Now"

     

    Can Debt Cure a Problem Created by Debt?

     

    One of the common arguments against fiscal policy in the current situation—one that sounds sensible—runs like this: “You yourself say that this crisis is the result of too much debt. Now you’re saying that the answer involves running up even more debt. That can’t possibly make sense.” Actually, it does.

    But to explain why will take both some careful thinking and a look at the historical record. It’s true that people like me believe that the depression we’re in was in large part caused by the buildup of household debt, which set the stage for a Minksy moment in which highly indebted households were forced to slash their spending. How, then, can even more debt be part of the appropriate policy response?

     

    The key point is that this argument against deficit spending assumes, implicitly, that debt is debt—that it doesn’t matter who owes the money. Yet that can’t be right; if it were, we wouldn’t have a problem in the first place. After all, to a first approximation debt is money we owe to ourselves; yes, the United States has debt to China and other countries, but as we saw in chapter 3, our net debt to foreigners is relatively small and not at the heart of the problem. Ignoring the foreign component, or looking at the world as a whole, we see that the overall level of debt makes no difference to aggregate net worth—one person’s liability is another person’s asset. It follows that the level of debt matters only if the distribution of net worth matters, if highly indebted players face different constraints from players with low debt. And this means that all debt isn’t created equal, which is why borrowing by some actors now can help cure problems created by excess borrowing by other actors in the past. Think of it this way: when debt is rising, it’s not the economy as a whole borrowing more money. It is, rather, a case of less patient people —people who for whatever reason want to spend sooner rather than later—borrowing from more patient people. The main limit on this kind of borrowing is the concern of those patient lenders about whether they will be repaid, which sets some kind of ceiling on each individual’s ability to borrow.

     

    What happened in 2008 was a sudden downward revision of those ceilings. This downward revision has forced the debtors to pay down their debt, rapidly, which means spending much less. And the problem is that the creditors don’t face any equivalent incentive to spend more. Low interest rates help, but because of the severity of the “deleveraging shock,” even a zero interest rate isn’t low enough to get them to fill the hole left by the collapse in debtors’ demand. The result isn’t just a depressed economy: low incomes and low inflation (or even deflation) make it that much harder for the debtors to pay down their debt. What can be done? One answer is to find some way to reduce the real value of the debt. Debt relief could do this; so could inflation, if you can get it, which would do two things: it would make it possible to have a negative real interest rate, and it would in itself erode the outstanding debt. Yes, that would in a way be rewarding debtors for their past excesses, but economics is not a morality play. I’ll have more to say about inflation in the next chapter.

     

    Just to go back for a moment to my point that debt is not all the same: yes, debt relief would reduce the assets of the creditors at the same time, and by the same amount, as it reduced the liabilities of the debtors. But the debtors are being forced to cut spending, while the creditors aren’t, so this is a net positive for economy wide spending. But what if neither inflation nor sufficient debt relief can, or at any rate will, be delivered? Well, suppose a third party can come in: the government. Suppose that it can borrow for a while, using the borrowed money to buy useful things like rail tunnels under the Hudson, or pay schoolteacher salaries. The true social cost of these things will be very low, because the government will be employing resources that would otherwise be unemployed. And it also makes it easier for the debtors to pay down their debt; if the government maintains its spending long enough, it can bring debtors to the point where they’re no longer being forced into emergency debt reduction and where further deficit spending is no longer required to achieve full employment. Yes, private debt will in part have been replaced by public debt, but the point is that debt will have been shifted away from the players whose debt is doing the economic damage, so that the economy’s problems will have been reduced even if the overall level of debt hasn’t fallen.

     

    The bottom line, then, is that the plausible-sounding argument that debt can’t cure debt is just wrong. On the contrary, it can—and the alternative is a prolonged period of economic weakness that actually makes the debt problem harder to resolve.

     

    I have been pissed off with Krugman's columns in NYT for various reasons (too partisan) but his book is a gem.

     

    Vinod

  16. If you are going to index then at the very least you need to keep up to date on GMO's asset class forecasts. If you are going to be putting small amounts of money over very long periods of time, then this might not be needed, but if you are going to put say significant amounts then you need to pay attention to valuation.

     

    Other choice is go with DFA Funds and focus on value indexes. They have pretty good funds although for the wrong reasons (Fama French nonsense...).

     

    Vinod

  17.  

    But you raise an interesting point.  I think there are many on the boards who equate "proper" investing with Buffett and Munger.  So a focused portfolio that one buys and holds until the earlier of eternity or a reason for the investment thesis changing.  That's one way to do it.  It's a damn good way if you can do it, but it never made sense to me.  I don't want to buy something that's arguably 2% below fair value today and let it compound for years.  I can't see the future in that way.  I would rather buy something at 50-60 cents on the dollar and let it revert to the mean.  Then I sell.

     

    Graham also said that he buys his stocks like he buys groceries, not perfume.  That was always one of my favorite sayings from him.  I have always envisioned myself as running a grocery store or something.  My inventory is my stocks.  In one aisle you may have the high end filets and lobsters, but in another aisle is the gum and candy and paper plates.  To me it's all good.  What do I care what someone buys?  Come into my store and buy a pack of gum.  Sure, I might just make 2 cents on that, but gum sells all day long and it doesn't take a lot of time to determine your gum inventory.  You buy it, you stick it on the shelf and someone will buy it from you.  It doesn't take long to track it. 

     

    So for me, businesslike is treating my investing as a business.  Our difference, if we actually even have one, is that you are equating each stock you own as if you ran the business while I see it as inventory.  While I do fervently believe that each stock I own is an ownership in a business, it is also just a piece of paper.  It's both, Graham says that as well.  We have the best of both worlds.  So I buy thinking of the business, but then put it on the shelf.  Everything is for sale!  I run things professionally and can't imagine running it in any more businesslike manner.

     

     

    Kraven - I like your analogy so much that I copied it into my notes.

     

    Thanks

     

    Vinod

  18. Agree Vinod, but don't you find strange a level of hedge fund underperformance that is way more that could be justified by fees and transactions costs? And studies of retail investors buy high / sell low of mutual funds underperformance is in the hundreds of bps per year over the manager underperformance. Who is picking this performance, just hedge fund managers' 2/20?

     

    Not really. I think most hedge funds operate to shoot the lights out, leveraging to the hilt due to the incentive structure of 2/20. If they blow up, they start anew. So in any period where a black swan type event shows up, hedge funds under perform. On the other hand when everything goes well they outperform. This is just another version of "Dunn's law of mutual fund performance" applied to hedge funds.

     

    Dunn's Law states that “When an asset class does relatively well, an index fund in the asset class does even better. In contrast, when an asset class does poorly, the active managers do better in that asset class.”

     

    http://www.efficientfrontier.com/ef/400/dlr.htm

     

    Vinod

     

×
×
  • Create New...